Thursday, August 27, 2009
National Anti-SEZ Network in the Making?
---------------------------------------
Dear Friends and Colleagues,
We are pleased to invite you to a People’s Audit of SEZs in Maharashtra on September 15, 2009 at Pen Taluka in Raigad District.
As you may know, Maharashtra has the largest number of approved SEZs in the country to date: 202. This People’s Audit, along with an eminent panel, will critically examine issues emerging around large SEZs, of land acquisition; displacement; corruption; environmental impact; compensation as well as questions of development and economic growth from 4 districts in Maharashtra: Raigad, Gorai, Nasik and Poona.
Your participation and engagement would prove extremely valuable in critically examining the unfolding political economy of SEZs and in articulating the development needs of the State. We hope that you will join us in this process and since this is a largely campaign based initiative we are requesting participants to find support for travel to Mumbai. We will make all necessary arrangements for your food and stay within the area and travel from Mumbai to Raigad and back.
This effort has been jointly initiated by the Jagatikaran Virodhi Kriti Samiti (JVKS; alliance of several peasant organizations in SEZ areas in Maharashtra), National Alliance of People's Movements (NAPM), the National Campaign for People's Right to Information (NCPRI), the Tata Institute of Social Sciences (TISS), National Centre for Advocacy Studies (NCAS) and the India Centre for Human Rights Lawyers Network (ICHRLN).
Brief Background:
The SEZ Act was enacted in India in 2005 and since, 722 SEZs have already been approved in the country with many in various stages of approval, land acquisition or completion as the case may be. SEZs have invited controversy and peasant resistance in many quarters and have become bones of contention between the state, the developers and ordinary citizens.
To recap some of the features of the law: the Special Economic Zone Act 2005 deems SEZs as “public purpose.” The definition of manufacturing in the Act includes manufacturing and production processes, and includes agriculture, aquaculture, animal husbandry, floriculture, horticulture, pisciculture, poultry, sericulture, viticulture, mining and services. This comprehensive inclusion of all types of economic activities within the purview of SEZs, comes with no restrictions on the maximum size and numbers of SEZs and a requirement of only 50% of the proposed land to be dedicated to economic activity. SEZs do not have any local body representation; nor adequate representation of labour and environmental concerns in their administrative structure. The Act contains provisions like section 31(9) that further remove accountability mechanisms from the Zone Authority: “No act or proceeding of an Authority shall be invalidated merely by reason of—a) any vacancy in, or any defect in the constitution of, the Authority; or b) any defect in the appointment of a person acting as a Member of the Authority; or c) any irregularity in the procedure of the Authority not affecting the merits of the case.”
What has been the impact of this radical legislation? Given the potentially large scale implications and the nature of "development" envisaged by the SEZ Act in the country, the NAPM, the NCPRI, TISS, ICHRLN, NCAS, JVKS and several other groups and organisations from across the states and SEZ areas met early last month to initiate a national People’s Audit on SEZs process in India. The Maharashtra People’s Audit is first in a series that will be followed by similar exercises in Goa, Guajarat, Andhra Pradesh, Tamil Nadu, Karnataka, Orissa, West Bengal and Delhi. The People’s Audits will seek to examine the impact of the projects against stated objectives, as well as the impact of the law on the people of the area, and the political economy of the country.
Looking forward to your kind participation on September 15.
Warm Regards,
Ulka Mahajan and Sampat Kale
---------------------------------------------------
People’s Audit of SEZs in Maharashtra
Time and Date: 11:00 am — 6:00 pm; September 15, 2009
Venue: Div Village, Pen Taluka, District Raigad, Maharashtra
Travel to the Venue: Div Village is 1 hr (40 km) from Panvel in Mumbai by road on the Mumbai-Goa highway. There are regular buses to Pen town from Mumbai Central, Sion and Chembur Maitri Park bus stations. From Pen frequent 6-seaters are available outside the bus station to Div Village.
Travel Arrangements will also be made by TISS for 15th morning at 8 am. Kindly reach the main porch of TISS in time to avail of the same. The Tata Institute of Social sciences (Main campus) is situated opposite the Deonar Bus Depot on V.N. Purav Marg (earlier known as the Sion-Trombay Road).
For more details please contact Sampat Kale: 9423202202; Ulka Mahajan: 9869232478; Shiva Dhakal: 9011596707; Simpreet Singh: 9969363065; Preeti Sampat: 9004071740
Tuesday, August 25, 2009
More Thinking Small
In a sense, this IS mainly a question of administrative coherence, since it makes no sense to allow an SEZ to generate power if it cannot distribute it. On the other hand, this eventuality had been foreseen at the time the SEZ Act 2005 was passed, and it was specifically decided that state governments, who feared (with good reason, as it turned out) that their prerogatives would be undermined by certain aspects of the SEZ movement. Perhaps most importantly, the Development Commissioners may be in a position to take over decision-making responsibility over the implementation of various functions within their SEZs. Labour and environmental clearances are the ones most frequently mentioned. This can, potentially, amount to something approaching policymaking control once implementation decisions begin to acquire a particular bent in terms of how they interpret existing policy. So to the extent that this new decision on electricity-distribution claws back from state governments an important veto point -- the withholding of which could be used by states to force compliance by SEZ promoters with other agenda items outside their purview -- it is a substantial matter.
This process of fostering the accretion of layers of small policy change -- decisions which nevertheless have a HUGE impact not just on government actors such as state government departments, but also of course the corporate interests involved -- is consistence with earlier practice, some examples of which can be found in earlier blog posts. It is also an extension of the logic of reforming by stealth, which has characterised the politics of reform in India for many years now. While such a strategy would seem to have a diminishing shelf life over time -- and it does -- it is proving remarkably effective in keeping the potential political opposition to SEZs wrong-footed. Despite the protests on certain egregious projects, the ability of opposition parties at the national level to hit at the core of the SEZ phenomenon is striking. Senior BJP members, including former ministers in the NDA government, have called attention to the party leadership's inability to make headway on this or any other issues.
Wednesday, August 12, 2009
The God of Small Things
Economic crises has, in fact, become something of a catch-all excuse for any number of policy revisions and discretionary decisions, including extensions on the amount of time within which SEZs must be developed, and rules governing external commercial borrowing by SEZ promoters. To avoid the appearance of favoring business interests, rule changes are often packaged alongside restrictive conditions of various types. For instance, the relaxation on external commercial borrowings on 'infrastructure' are limited to non-residential/non-commercial-real-estate portions of the SEZ; they cannot be applied, for instance, to Integrated Model Townships. Because money is fungible, the logic implicit in this restriction (that the Government of India and Reserve Bank do not want to encourage speculative investment in residential developments) is undercut in practice.
Pro-industry rule changes are also coupled with what are meant to be perceived as countervailing get-tough policies to ensure compliance with new or existing rules by those actors to whom concessions are being granted. Vowing to crack down on firms that have violated ECB norms, a statement by the Finance Ministry declared that the government will revoke access to the 'automatic route' (i.e., non-licensed procedure) for overseas loansby such companies. According to the statement: 'Currently, the ECB policy is not explicit about accessing of ECB by the corporates, which have violated the extant ECB policy and are under investigation by the Reserve Bank and or Directorate of Enforcement'; henceforth, however, a 'request by such corporates for ECB will be examined under the approval route', which hardly seems like a harsh punishment -- except insofar as the approval route will tend to result in demands for illicit payments by those granting these approvals. A strange form of disincentive, to be sure, but possibly effective.
Tuesday, August 11, 2009
Finding the Reverse Gear: Precedent-Setting on Denotification
Just this week, the Board of Approvals announced that it would allow the the withdrawal of the Matyas biotech SEZ planned for Hyderabad that had been promoted by the relatives of the former head of IT giant Satyam. Whether there is a distinction between withdrawal and denotification is unclear. Presumably it matters which party initiates the request for denotification -- that is, the promoter or the state goverment. But in the Goa case, where the state government was a co-promoter in at least some of the SEZs, this distinction is less meaningful.
The bureaucratic machinery charged with implementing and overseeing the SEZ policy is making up the rules as it goes along. There is nothing inherently wrong with that, unless you believe that those framing the initial legislation and regulatory guildelines should foresee every potential contingency. On the other hand, it is perfectly legitimate to ask whether, in the process of framing and revising officials rules -- whether with regard to SEZs or any other policy domain -- biases manifest themselves. In the case of SEZs, it will be important to track whether the pressing concerns for equity and transparency among civil society receive the same treatment as corporate interests.
Monday, August 10, 2009
Vague Nods to Corporate Social Responsibility
There are a few indications that at least some SEZ developers are at least aware of the complaints levelled against them, and want to be seen to be taking some kind of positive action. The promoters of Sri City, a 5000+ acre mega SEZ, near the border between Tamil Nadu and Andhra Pradesh, took the trouble to identify the availability of housing within the residential portion of the SEZ for 'workers' (as well as for executives, who are routinely catered for). But how many 'workers' will indeed be covered? What about those who will be employed in ancillary service industries that will (if the development is successful) grow up around the walls of the SEZ? What options will workers in the informal sector? These and other questions ought to be part of the master plan for the regions in which SEZs are located, but (as the research of Dr N Sridharan, a professor of Urban Planning at Delhi's School of Planning and Architecture, has shown), efforts to plan for such eventualities are rarely seen. (Dr Sridharan's work is one of the components of the research project with which this blog is affiliated).
The firm's public relations presentation to an investment summit also highlighted its concern for the surrounding environment, noting that limited-carbon-impact was its goal. Towards this end, the developers were planting 1 million saplings on the 800-acre designated 'green' area within the SEZ. Whether such pro-environment trappings would be sufficient, given the huge water resources that the industrial sites within the SEZ would require, is open to question. Moreover, as production of automobile components is one of the sectoral thrusts of the SEZ, the project can hardly be called 'green.'
Thursday, August 6, 2009
Informative Discussion of SEZ Land Issues
The discussion in this case included some very incisive points about the various aspects of India's Resettlement and Rehabilitation policy, of which compensation (to the individuals whose physical assets are being acquired) is just one part. The social dimensions (rebuilding the social fabric) and the question of sustainable livelihoods (for all project affected people) were also touched upon.
But there was, in fact, very little by way of an answer to the question posed above -- as to why opposition arises in some cases and not others. The obliquely supplied answer was that when private companies acquire land on their own they have been more attentive to these complex issues than when government does the acquiring on their behalf. A contrast was drawn between the Tata Nano (Singur) project (which, incidentally, was NOT an SEZ), where the West Bengal government acquired the land (or sought to), and the Jindal Steel plant (where the firms purchased land directly, placing some of the funds in reserve rather than paying out all at once). Whether this pattern (state bad, corporate good) is discernable among a larger set of cases is open to question. Especially given that many corporate land acquirers do not in fact attend to the multiple dimensions of rehabilitation mentioned above.
The second article in the series, 'Land acquisition and legislative lapses', looks at the legal issues involved in land acquisition for SEZs. Among other things, the discussion with LiveMint.com's editors included this striking opinion from CEO and Managing Director of IDFC, Rajiv Lall:
'What has happened in our country is that starting with that concept [SEZs], by the time you’ve got to the legislation [The SEZ Act 2005], you’ve completely distorted the notion of SEZ.The launch of the report, where among the speakers was Kamal Nath (former Commerce Minister, now in charge of infrastructure -- a smooth transition thematically, if nevertheless viewed as a demotion, politically), was also covered on LiveMint.com. It includes video extracts which are quite revealing, not least about the Government of India's current intentions regarding reform/amendment of the Land Acquisition Act and reintroduction of the Resettlement and Rehabilitation Act. The former has run into some trouble, in the form of opposition from Mamata Banerjee, who led the anti-Nandigram agitations and whose Trinamul Congress is a member of the UPA.So along the way, because of interventions of a lot of vested interests, what you have created is legislation that allows for, technically, the creation of SEZs that have nothing to do with the original concept. Hence, the allegations or the suggestions that “Oh, this is just a scheme either to avoid taxes”—because one of the fiscal benefits associated with getting that status is a whole bunch of tax exemptions—or that it is a land grab in which you effectively change the land use and hence enhance the land value....
I think the allegation that the legislation has been completely distorted to undermine the original noble purpose of the initiative is the correct interpretation. So I don’t think I am a particular fan of the existing legislation.'
Calcutta Art Exhibit on SEZs
Wednesday, August 5, 2009
A Question of Time?
It is clear, however, that in both cases, other factors have been at work. The Reliance-Haryana project has been beset with problems from the outset, including slow acquisition of land, the changing size-ceiling norms under the SEZ Act's amended rules, frictions with the state government, and charges of corruption (leveled by Bhajan Lal's son, no less).
The Quark City project in neighbouring Punjab is also facing delays arising from a broadly similar set of constraints, though the size issue is of a different magnitude (it is much smaller). The fact that Quark's promoters also have two other SEZs under development in the state may influence the decision on their request for more time.
There are other cases elsewhere in India where extensions will be needed/requested. A key issue will be the attitude of the state governments concerned (thought the official decision on whether to grant an extension rests with the BoA in Delhi). It will be revealing, perhaps, to see how inclined state governments are to accommodate the various promoters -- particularly in states where elections have seen a new party or coalition come to power.
Tuesday, August 4, 2009
SEZs and Labour Laws
Singh makes the point that businesses have found all kinds of ways of avoiding labour laws -- including contracting out, casualization, and collusion with labour inspectors, among other techniques. This is consistent with arguments concerning the politics of liberalization which stress that India has witnessed over the past two decades a process of policy change that can best be described as 'reform by stealth'. The ability to evade labour regulations effectively, Singh points out, has been 'assisted to various degrees by ongoing executive and judicial practice'.
Singh's larger point is that SEZs take this logic a step further by blurring the formal-informal distinction in practice:
'Given the overall desire of the SEZ endeavour to push for labour-intensive export oriented consumer goods, the entire enterprise is probably best understood as being located at the border between the formal and informal sectors, drawing the labour force from the informal/agricultural sector. At this location, the very act of employment generates a dilemma because the instant a worker is drawn from the informal/agricultural sector and ‘employed’, she becomes eligible for all the benefits provided by law to formal sector workers. If this were indeed to be allowed, it would raise perceived labour costs which would presumably dampen national and international investment. If disallowed explicitly, the political rhetoric associated with the SEZ enterprise would end up being more widely challenged. Given the frontier location of the labour involved, the solution to this dilemma has been to nudge the practice of law in a manner which minimises the coverage of labour law without actually changing the law—a relatively smoothly accomplished step, given the nature of Indian labour law as well as the structure of the enabling law associated with SEZs.
'Though the Special Economic Zones Act, 2005 overrides certain other laws (particularly granting fiscal benefits to firms located in a SEZ), the Act maintains that in relation to labour, standard labour laws are to continue to operate in the SEZs. While there is no change in the laws, under this regime the implementation of labour law is shifted from the control of the Labour Commissioner to the Development Commissioner of the SEZ, a figure who is given substantial power over all aspects of governance of the SEZ. Furthermore, the ability of workers to organise strikes is curtailed by undertaking a general policy measure that labels economic activity within a SEZ as a ‘public utility service’, which under Indian law makes strikes in units labelled as such entirely illegal. All these factors taken together result in the fact that while the ‘speak’ says that labour laws are supposed to be operational in a SEZ, they are almost entirely absent in practice.'
Singh goes on to discuss a variety of studies of labour practicies within SEZs. The literature on India's SEZs is thin, largely because the SEZ Act is so new, having been passed only in 2005. Still, some of the pre-2005 Export Processing Zones (which had been converted to SEZs following a change to the Export-Import policy of 2002) have been around long enough to have attracted the scrutiny of scholars.
Singh cites, in particular, Padmini Swaminathan (2005) “The Trauma of ‘Wage Employment’ and the ‘Burden of Work’ for Women in India” in Kalpana Kannabiran (ed.) The Violence of Normal Times: Essays on Women’s Lived Realities, New Delhi, Women Unlimited). In terms of the net impact on women's well-being, the study paints a mixed picture. But in terms of the application of labour laws to SEZs, the sense is that enforcement mechanisms are even weaker than in the formal economy as a whole, though (in a de facto sense) clearly have more of an impact than the non-existent regime affecting the informal sector. All of this refers to the pre-2005 SEZ Act dispensation, which may be a different animal altogether.
Monday, August 3, 2009
Can Bangladesh Competition Increase Pressure on India's States to Provide More Sops to SEZ Promoters
A combination of these two levels of inter-jurisdictional competition -- between countries, and between regions within countries -- appears to be on the rise in South Asia at the moment. Not only has the SEZ policy of Sri Lanka been something of interest to investors (and state governments in India eager to attract them), now Bangladesh has upped the ante. Prime Minister Sheikh Hasina Wajed came out recently with a directly competitive statement, claiming that SEZ promoters who may have wanted to set up shop in India should consider coming across the border to Bangladesh.
Interestingly, it is the SEZ-related political problems encountered by the neighbouring state of West Bengal -- primarily, but not exclusively, stemming from the Nandigram SEZ -- which has animated the Prime Minister's statement. That Bangladesh provides a more conducive and stable policy environment in which to do business is surely a slap in the face of the West Bengal authorities, as well as an indirect slight (palliative words by the PM notwithstanding) to India's Railways Minister, Mamata Banerjee, who spearheaded the anti-Nandigram resistance.
SEZs and Demonstration Effecs, Economic and Political
It is increasingly clear, however, that this logic can cut both ways, particularly when the political dimensions of SEZs are taken into account. First there was the argument, voiced at the time the SEZ policy was first being introduced, claiming that the narrow applicability of these policies (limited only to 'special zones') is an admission that the architects of the SEZ policy were well aware that the country at large was not politically ready for such far-reaching policy change.
Second, the resistance movement that have sprung up during the implementation of the SEZ policy -- particularly with respect to land acquisition -- have led to speculation that the SEZ approach may spur a negative demonstration effect, politically speaking. That is, the SEZ experience has highlighted the high political costs of pushing through these policy measures, even in the geographically circumscribed form they have taken thus far. This can put governing elites off the idea of more radical economic reforms for the economy writ large.
A newer position has been staked out by market-friendly commentators, including two Harvard Business School professors, writing in the Christian Science Monitor. They argue that the political controversies that have arisen in implementing the SEZ policy shows that, in fact, a MORE radical approach to policy reform is needed -- one note confined to special zones. Briefly recapping the opposition to SEZs in a number of regions, they ask: 'Considering how thorny the issue has become...Does India really need them?' Their answer is that 'The best policy for the government may be to provide the benefits of SEZs – low tariffs, reasonable taxes, good infrastructure, little red tape – to all firms in all parts of the country.' The authors do not spell out how opposition to such policies, if pursued nationally, could be overcome.
It is nevertheless intriguing to see friends of liberalization taking the position that SEZs may not be worth the political costs they inevitably impose.