Monday, August 10, 2009
Vague Nods to Corporate Social Responsibility
There are a few indications that at least some SEZ developers are at least aware of the complaints levelled against them, and want to be seen to be taking some kind of positive action. The promoters of Sri City, a 5000+ acre mega SEZ, near the border between Tamil Nadu and Andhra Pradesh, took the trouble to identify the availability of housing within the residential portion of the SEZ for 'workers' (as well as for executives, who are routinely catered for). But how many 'workers' will indeed be covered? What about those who will be employed in ancillary service industries that will (if the development is successful) grow up around the walls of the SEZ? What options will workers in the informal sector? These and other questions ought to be part of the master plan for the regions in which SEZs are located, but (as the research of Dr N Sridharan, a professor of Urban Planning at Delhi's School of Planning and Architecture, has shown), efforts to plan for such eventualities are rarely seen. (Dr Sridharan's work is one of the components of the research project with which this blog is affiliated).
The firm's public relations presentation to an investment summit also highlighted its concern for the surrounding environment, noting that limited-carbon-impact was its goal. Towards this end, the developers were planting 1 million saplings on the 800-acre designated 'green' area within the SEZ. Whether such pro-environment trappings would be sufficient, given the huge water resources that the industrial sites within the SEZ would require, is open to question. Moreover, as production of automobile components is one of the sectoral thrusts of the SEZ, the project can hardly be called 'green.'
Thursday, August 6, 2009
Informative Discussion of SEZ Land Issues
The discussion in this case included some very incisive points about the various aspects of India's Resettlement and Rehabilitation policy, of which compensation (to the individuals whose physical assets are being acquired) is just one part. The social dimensions (rebuilding the social fabric) and the question of sustainable livelihoods (for all project affected people) were also touched upon.
But there was, in fact, very little by way of an answer to the question posed above -- as to why opposition arises in some cases and not others. The obliquely supplied answer was that when private companies acquire land on their own they have been more attentive to these complex issues than when government does the acquiring on their behalf. A contrast was drawn between the Tata Nano (Singur) project (which, incidentally, was NOT an SEZ), where the West Bengal government acquired the land (or sought to), and the Jindal Steel plant (where the firms purchased land directly, placing some of the funds in reserve rather than paying out all at once). Whether this pattern (state bad, corporate good) is discernable among a larger set of cases is open to question. Especially given that many corporate land acquirers do not in fact attend to the multiple dimensions of rehabilitation mentioned above.
The second article in the series, 'Land acquisition and legislative lapses', looks at the legal issues involved in land acquisition for SEZs. Among other things, the discussion with LiveMint.com's editors included this striking opinion from CEO and Managing Director of IDFC, Rajiv Lall:
'What has happened in our country is that starting with that concept [SEZs], by the time you’ve got to the legislation [The SEZ Act 2005], you’ve completely distorted the notion of SEZ.The launch of the report, where among the speakers was Kamal Nath (former Commerce Minister, now in charge of infrastructure -- a smooth transition thematically, if nevertheless viewed as a demotion, politically), was also covered on LiveMint.com. It includes video extracts which are quite revealing, not least about the Government of India's current intentions regarding reform/amendment of the Land Acquisition Act and reintroduction of the Resettlement and Rehabilitation Act. The former has run into some trouble, in the form of opposition from Mamata Banerjee, who led the anti-Nandigram agitations and whose Trinamul Congress is a member of the UPA.So along the way, because of interventions of a lot of vested interests, what you have created is legislation that allows for, technically, the creation of SEZs that have nothing to do with the original concept. Hence, the allegations or the suggestions that “Oh, this is just a scheme either to avoid taxes”—because one of the fiscal benefits associated with getting that status is a whole bunch of tax exemptions—or that it is a land grab in which you effectively change the land use and hence enhance the land value....
I think the allegation that the legislation has been completely distorted to undermine the original noble purpose of the initiative is the correct interpretation. So I don’t think I am a particular fan of the existing legislation.'
Calcutta Art Exhibit on SEZs
Wednesday, August 5, 2009
A Question of Time?
It is clear, however, that in both cases, other factors have been at work. The Reliance-Haryana project has been beset with problems from the outset, including slow acquisition of land, the changing size-ceiling norms under the SEZ Act's amended rules, frictions with the state government, and charges of corruption (leveled by Bhajan Lal's son, no less).
The Quark City project in neighbouring Punjab is also facing delays arising from a broadly similar set of constraints, though the size issue is of a different magnitude (it is much smaller). The fact that Quark's promoters also have two other SEZs under development in the state may influence the decision on their request for more time.
There are other cases elsewhere in India where extensions will be needed/requested. A key issue will be the attitude of the state governments concerned (thought the official decision on whether to grant an extension rests with the BoA in Delhi). It will be revealing, perhaps, to see how inclined state governments are to accommodate the various promoters -- particularly in states where elections have seen a new party or coalition come to power.
Tuesday, August 4, 2009
SEZs and Labour Laws
Singh makes the point that businesses have found all kinds of ways of avoiding labour laws -- including contracting out, casualization, and collusion with labour inspectors, among other techniques. This is consistent with arguments concerning the politics of liberalization which stress that India has witnessed over the past two decades a process of policy change that can best be described as 'reform by stealth'. The ability to evade labour regulations effectively, Singh points out, has been 'assisted to various degrees by ongoing executive and judicial practice'.
Singh's larger point is that SEZs take this logic a step further by blurring the formal-informal distinction in practice:
'Given the overall desire of the SEZ endeavour to push for labour-intensive export oriented consumer goods, the entire enterprise is probably best understood as being located at the border between the formal and informal sectors, drawing the labour force from the informal/agricultural sector. At this location, the very act of employment generates a dilemma because the instant a worker is drawn from the informal/agricultural sector and ‘employed’, she becomes eligible for all the benefits provided by law to formal sector workers. If this were indeed to be allowed, it would raise perceived labour costs which would presumably dampen national and international investment. If disallowed explicitly, the political rhetoric associated with the SEZ enterprise would end up being more widely challenged. Given the frontier location of the labour involved, the solution to this dilemma has been to nudge the practice of law in a manner which minimises the coverage of labour law without actually changing the law—a relatively smoothly accomplished step, given the nature of Indian labour law as well as the structure of the enabling law associated with SEZs.
'Though the Special Economic Zones Act, 2005 overrides certain other laws (particularly granting fiscal benefits to firms located in a SEZ), the Act maintains that in relation to labour, standard labour laws are to continue to operate in the SEZs. While there is no change in the laws, under this regime the implementation of labour law is shifted from the control of the Labour Commissioner to the Development Commissioner of the SEZ, a figure who is given substantial power over all aspects of governance of the SEZ. Furthermore, the ability of workers to organise strikes is curtailed by undertaking a general policy measure that labels economic activity within a SEZ as a ‘public utility service’, which under Indian law makes strikes in units labelled as such entirely illegal. All these factors taken together result in the fact that while the ‘speak’ says that labour laws are supposed to be operational in a SEZ, they are almost entirely absent in practice.'
Singh goes on to discuss a variety of studies of labour practicies within SEZs. The literature on India's SEZs is thin, largely because the SEZ Act is so new, having been passed only in 2005. Still, some of the pre-2005 Export Processing Zones (which had been converted to SEZs following a change to the Export-Import policy of 2002) have been around long enough to have attracted the scrutiny of scholars.
Singh cites, in particular, Padmini Swaminathan (2005) “The Trauma of ‘Wage Employment’ and the ‘Burden of Work’ for Women in India” in Kalpana Kannabiran (ed.) The Violence of Normal Times: Essays on Women’s Lived Realities, New Delhi, Women Unlimited). In terms of the net impact on women's well-being, the study paints a mixed picture. But in terms of the application of labour laws to SEZs, the sense is that enforcement mechanisms are even weaker than in the formal economy as a whole, though (in a de facto sense) clearly have more of an impact than the non-existent regime affecting the informal sector. All of this refers to the pre-2005 SEZ Act dispensation, which may be a different animal altogether.
Monday, August 3, 2009
Can Bangladesh Competition Increase Pressure on India's States to Provide More Sops to SEZ Promoters
A combination of these two levels of inter-jurisdictional competition -- between countries, and between regions within countries -- appears to be on the rise in South Asia at the moment. Not only has the SEZ policy of Sri Lanka been something of interest to investors (and state governments in India eager to attract them), now Bangladesh has upped the ante. Prime Minister Sheikh Hasina Wajed came out recently with a directly competitive statement, claiming that SEZ promoters who may have wanted to set up shop in India should consider coming across the border to Bangladesh.
Interestingly, it is the SEZ-related political problems encountered by the neighbouring state of West Bengal -- primarily, but not exclusively, stemming from the Nandigram SEZ -- which has animated the Prime Minister's statement. That Bangladesh provides a more conducive and stable policy environment in which to do business is surely a slap in the face of the West Bengal authorities, as well as an indirect slight (palliative words by the PM notwithstanding) to India's Railways Minister, Mamata Banerjee, who spearheaded the anti-Nandigram resistance.
SEZs and Demonstration Effecs, Economic and Political
It is increasingly clear, however, that this logic can cut both ways, particularly when the political dimensions of SEZs are taken into account. First there was the argument, voiced at the time the SEZ policy was first being introduced, claiming that the narrow applicability of these policies (limited only to 'special zones') is an admission that the architects of the SEZ policy were well aware that the country at large was not politically ready for such far-reaching policy change.
Second, the resistance movement that have sprung up during the implementation of the SEZ policy -- particularly with respect to land acquisition -- have led to speculation that the SEZ approach may spur a negative demonstration effect, politically speaking. That is, the SEZ experience has highlighted the high political costs of pushing through these policy measures, even in the geographically circumscribed form they have taken thus far. This can put governing elites off the idea of more radical economic reforms for the economy writ large.
A newer position has been staked out by market-friendly commentators, including two Harvard Business School professors, writing in the Christian Science Monitor. They argue that the political controversies that have arisen in implementing the SEZ policy shows that, in fact, a MORE radical approach to policy reform is needed -- one note confined to special zones. Briefly recapping the opposition to SEZs in a number of regions, they ask: 'Considering how thorny the issue has become...Does India really need them?' Their answer is that 'The best policy for the government may be to provide the benefits of SEZs – low tariffs, reasonable taxes, good infrastructure, little red tape – to all firms in all parts of the country.' The authors do not spell out how opposition to such policies, if pursued nationally, could be overcome.
It is nevertheless intriguing to see friends of liberalization taking the position that SEZs may not be worth the political costs they inevitably impose.